|
Showing 1 - 11 of
11 matches in All Departments
Both of the authors found themselves savagely "canceled" by their
peers in Japanese studies programs in the U.S. for refusing to
follow the Woke line on the World War II "comfort
women."Â Â Contrary to the party line in American
humanities departments, the women were not
slaves.  They were prostitutes.  And the
notion that they were anything but prostitutes owes itself to a
hoax perpetrated by a Japanese communist author in the
1980s.  Any serious Japanese intellectual (of any
political perspective) understands this, and many intellectuals in
South Korea understand it as well.  It is a mark of the
intellectual bankruptcy of the hyper-politicized humanities
departments that they continue to cling to this 1980s-vintage hoax.
      Through its "comfort
women" framework, the Japanese military extended its licensing
regime for domestic brothels to the brothels next to its overseas
bases.  Through that regime, it imposed the strenuous
health standards it needed to control the venereal disease that had
debilitated its troops in earlier wars.  These "comfort
stations" recruited their prostitutes through variations on the
standard indenture contracts that the licensed brothels had used in
both Korea and Japan.  Some women took the jobs because
they were tricked by fraudulent recruiters.  Some took
them under pressure from abusive parents.  But the rest
seem to have taken the jobs for the money.
Employing a rational-choice approach, Professor Ramseyer studies the impact of Japanese law on economic growth in Japan. Toward that end, the author investigates the way law governed various markets, and the way that people negotiated contracts within those markets. Findings reveal that the legal system generally promoted mutually advantageous deals, and that people generally negotiated in ways that shrewdly promoted their private best interests. Whether in the markets for indentured servants, prostitutes, or marriage partners, this study reports little evidence of either age- or gender-related exploitation.
This statutory supplement includes statutes and rules relevant to
all business entities. It is suitable for use with all textbooks
and casebooks for such courses. It is includes all updates to the
statutes and rules.
Several years have passed since the 'store wars' over barriers to foreign products at Japanese distribution firms. Yet among English-speaking readers, how these firms operate remains a puzzle. In this book, the best Japanese scholars in their fields attempt to unravel that puzzle. Avoiding culture-based explanations, they employ a systematic and rigorous economic logic---yet, since they also avoid mathematical notation, the argument remains accessible to generalist readers.
Economic arrangements, Ramseyer writes, are structured and
implemented with the intent and hope that they will be carried out
with 'care, intelligence, discretion, and effort.' Yet
entrepreneurs work with partial information about the products, and
people, they are dealing with. Contracting in Japan illustrates
this by examining five sets of negotiations and unusual contractual
arrangements among non-specialist businessmen, and women, in Japan.
In it, Ramseyer explores how sake brewers were able to obtain and
market the necessary, but difficult-to-grow, sake rice that
captured the local terroir; how Buddhist temples tried to
compensate for rapidly falling donations by negotiating unusual
funerary contracts; and how pre-war local elites used leasing
instead of loans to fund local agriculture. Ramseyer examines these
entrepreneurs, discovering how they structured contracts, made
credible commitments, obtained valuable information, and protected
themselves from adverse consequences to create, maintain,
strengthen, and leverage the social networks in which they
operated.
Economic arrangements, Ramseyer writes, are structured and
implemented with the intent and hope that they will be carried out
with 'care, intelligence, discretion, and effort.' Yet
entrepreneurs work with partial information about the products, and
people, they are dealing with. Contracting in Japan illustrates
this by examining five sets of negotiations and unusual contractual
arrangements among non-specialist businessmen, and women, in Japan.
In it, Ramseyer explores how sake brewers were able to obtain and
market the necessary, but difficult-to-grow, sake rice that
captured the local terroir; how Buddhist temples tried to
compensate for rapidly falling donations by negotiating unusual
funerary contracts; and how pre-war local elites used leasing
instead of loans to fund local agriculture. Ramseyer examines these
entrepreneurs, discovering how they structured contracts, made
credible commitments, obtained valuable information, and protected
themselves from adverse consequences to create, maintain,
strengthen, and leverage the social networks in which they
operated.
Using a straightforward rational-choice approach, Professor
Ramseyer explores the impact that law had on various markets in
Japanese history and the effect that those markets had on economic
growth. In doing so, he applies an economic logic to markets in a
different world in a different historical period with a different
political regime and a different legal system. He looks hardest at
those markets that have most often struck traditional observers as
"exploitative" (e.g., the markets for indentured servants and for
sexual services). Within those markets, he focuses on the way
participants handled informational asymmetries in the contracting
process. Ramseyer finds that Japanese courts generally defined
important property rights clearly, and that Japanese markets
generally protected an individual's control over his or her own
labor. As a result, that the Japanese economy grew at relatively
efficient levels follows directly from standard economic theory. He
also concludes that the legal system usually promoted mutually
advantageous deals, and that market participants (whether poor or
rich, female or male) generally mitigated informational asymmetries
shrewdly by contract. He finds no systematic evidence of either
sex- or age-based exploitation.
In the latter-half of the nineteenth century and the first half of
the twentieth century, Japan underwent two major shifts in
political control. In the 1910s, the power of the oligarchy was
eclipsed by that of a larger group of professional politicians; in
the 1930s, the focus of power shifted again, this time to a set of
independent military leaders. In this book, Ramseyer and Rosenbluth
examine a key question of modern Japanese politics: why the Meiji
oligarchs were unable to design institutions capable of protecting
their power. The authors question why the oligarchs chose the
political institutions they did, and what the consequences of those
choices were for Japan's political competition, economic
development, and diplomatic relations. Indeed, they argue, it was
the oligarchs' very inability to agree among themselves on how to
rule that prompted them to cut the military loose from civilian
control - a decision that was to have disastrous consequences not
only for Japan but for the rest of the world. 1997 Winner of the
American Political Science Association Gregory Luebbert Prize for
the Best Book in Comparative Politics.
In the second half of the nineteenth century and the first half of
the twentieth, Japan underwent two major shifts in political
control. In the 1910s, the power of the oligarchy was eclipsed by
that of a larger group of professional politicians. In the 1930s,
the locus of power shifted again, this time to a set of independent
military leaders. In The Politics of Oligarchy, J. Mark Ramseyer
and Frances M. Rosenbluth examine a key question of modern Japanese
politics: Why were the Meiji oligarchs unable to design
institutions capable of protecting their power? Using an analytical
framework for oligarchic governments not specific to Japan, the
authors ask why the oligarchs chose the political institutions they
did, and what consequences those choices engendered for Japan's
political competition, economic development, and diplomatic
relations. Ramseyer and Rosenbluth argue that understanding these
shifts in power may clarify the general dynamics of oligarchic
government, as well as theoretical aspects of the relationship
between institutional structure and regime change.
When discussing Japanese politics or the Japanese legal system,
many scholars point to the peculiarities of the country's culture -
its need for consensus, its rejection of individualism, its
Confucian fascination with loyalty. Other scholars simply invent
new theories ad hoc to explain what they see. But is Japan really
so different that general social scientific theories don't apply?
Ramseyer and Rosenbluth don't think so, and in this book they show
how rational-choice theory can be applied to Japanese politics,
with telling results.
|
You may like...
The Expendables 4
Jason Statham, Sylvester Stallone
Blu-ray disc
R329
Discovery Miles 3 290
|