|
Showing 1 - 5 of
5 matches in All Departments
Foreword by Eric Maskin (Nobel Laureate in Economics, 2007)This
book is a collection of articles written by the two authors on the
topic of equality of opportunity. All articles build on the idea
that a just society should equalize the resources that determine
the opportunities agents face in order to follow their goals.
Resources are either external, like financial resources, or
internal, like preferences or skills. The authors propose to define
"equality of opportunity" as the combination of ethical principles
of compensation and responsibility. The principle of compensation
requires external resources to be used to compensate low-skilled
agents (considering that inequalities due to skill differences are
unjust). The principle of responsibility requires external
resources to be allocated without regards to inequalities due to
differences in preferences (considering that these inequalities are
not unjust). The articles present different ways of combining the
two principles in different economic contexts.The book offers many
possible aspects of the analysis of equality of opportunity,
ranging from axiomatic discussions in abstract compensation models,
to the design of redistribution policies in concrete labor income
taxation models.
What constitutes a good life? For most people, well-being involves
more than a high income or material prosperity alone. Many
non-material aspects, such as health, family life, living
environment, job quality and the meaningful use of time are at
least as important. Together, these factors also influence the
degree to which people are satisfied with their lives, and help to
determine how happy they feel. This book argues that happiness and
life satisfaction do not form a good basis for measuring
well-being, and proposes an alternative method that not only
considers the various aspects of well-being, but also the fact that
people have their own views on what is important in life. Not
limited just to theory, the book also presents a large-scale,
representative survey involving more than 3000 adults from over
2000 Belgian families, which charted the various aspects of the
individual well-being of Belgians. Focusing on the unequal
distribution of these various aspects of well-being within
families, the survey showed that some Belgians are more likely to
suffer from cumulative deprivation in multiple dimensions. Based on
this innovative study, the book describes which people in society
are worst off - and these are not necessarily only people on low
incomes or those who feel unhappy - and proposes that policymakers
prioritise these individuals.
The definition and measurement of social welfare have been a vexed
issue for the past century. This book makes a constructive, easily
applicable proposal and suggests how to evaluate the economic
situation of a society in a way that gives priority to the
worse-off and that respects each individual's preferences over his
or her own consumption, work, leisure and so on. This approach
resonates with the current concern to go 'beyond the GDP' in the
measurement of social progress. Compared to technical studies in
welfare economics, this book emphasizes constructive results rather
than paradoxes and impossibilities, and shows how one can start
from basic principles of efficiency and fairness and end up with
concrete evaluations of policies. Compared to more philosophical
treatments of social justice, this book is more precise about the
definition of social welfare and reaches conclusions about concrete
policies and institutions only after a rigorous derivation from
clearly stated principles.
What constitutes a good life? For most people, well-being involves
more than a high income or material prosperity alone. Many
non-material aspects, such as health, family life, living
environment, job quality and the meaningful use of time are at
least as important. Together, these factors also influence the
degree to which people are satisfied with their lives, and help to
determine how happy they feel. This book argues that happiness and
life satisfaction do not form a good basis for measuring
well-being, and proposes an alternative method that not only
considers the various aspects of well-being, but also the fact that
people have their own views on what is important in life. Not
limited just to theory, the book also presents a large-scale,
representative survey involving more than 3000 adults from over
2000 Belgian families, which charted the various aspects of the
individual well-being of Belgians. Focusing on the unequal
distribution of these various aspects of well-being within
families, the survey showed that some Belgians are more likely to
suffer from cumulative deprivation in multiple dimensions. Based on
this innovative study, the book describes which people in society
are worst off - and these are not necessarily only people on low
incomes or those who feel unhappy - and proposes that policymakers
prioritise these individuals.
The definition and measurement of social welfare have been a vexed
issue for the past century. This book makes a constructive, easily
applicable proposal and suggests how to evaluate the economic
situation of a society in a way that gives priority to the
worse-off and that respects each individual's preferences over his
or her own consumption, work, leisure, and so on. This approach
resonates with the current concern to go beyond the GDP in the
measurement of social progress. Compared to technical studies in
welfare economics, this book emphasizes constructive results rather
than paradoxes and impossibilities, and shows how one can start
from basic principles of efficiency and fairness and end up with
concrete evaluations of policies. Compared to more philosophical
treatments of social justice, this book is more precise about the
definition of social welfare and reaches conclusions about concrete
policies and institutions only after a rigorous derivation from
clearly stated principles.
|
|