|
Showing 1 - 6 of
6 matches in All Departments
Many economists and policymakers believe that the U.S. corporate
tax system is in need of reform. There is, however, disagreement
over why the corporate tax system needs to be reformed, and what
specific policy measures should be included in a reform. To assist
policymakers in designing and evaluating corporate tax proposals,
this report (1) briefly reviews the current U.S. corporate tax
system; (2) discusses economic factors that may be considered in
the corporate tax reform debate; and (3) presents corporate tax
reform policy options, including a brief discussion of current
corporate tax reform proposals. The current U.S. corporate income
tax system generally taxes corporate income at a rate of 35%. This
tax is applied to income earned domestically and abroad, although
taxes on certain income earned abroad can be deferred indefinitely
if that income remains overseas. The U.S. corporate tax system also
contains a number of deductions, exemptions, deferrals, and tax
credits, often referred to as "tax expenditures." Collectively,
these provisions reduce the effective tax rate paid by many U.S.
corporations below the 35% statutory rate. In 2011, the sum of all
corporate tax expenditures was $158.8 billion. The significance of
the corporate tax as a federal revenue source has declined over
time. At its post-WWII peak in 1952, the corporate tax generated
32.1% of all federal tax revenue. In 2010, the corporate tax
accounted for 8.9% of federal tax revenue. The decline in corporate
revenues is a combination of decreasing effective tax rates, an
increasing fraction of business activity that is being carried out
by pass-through entities (particularly partnerships and S
corporations, which are not subject to the corporate tax), and a
decline in corporate sector profitability. A particular aspect of
the corporate tax system that receives substantial attention is the
35% statutory corporate tax rate. Although the U.S. has the world's
highest statutory corporate tax rate, the U.S. effective corporate
tax rate is similar to the Organization for Economic Co-operation
and Development (OECD) average. Further, the U.S. collects less in
corporate tax revenue relative to Gross Domestic Production (GDP)
(1.9% in 2009) than the average of other OECD countries (2.8% in
2009). This report discusses a number of economic considerations
that may be made while evaluating various corporate tax reform
proposals. These might include analyses of the likely effect on
households of certain reforms (also known as incidence analysis).
Policymakers might also want to consider how certain corporate tax
provisions contribute to the allocation of economic resources,
choosing policies that promote an efficient use of resources. Other
goals of corporate tax reform may include designing a system that
is simple to comply with and administer, while also promoting
competitiveness of U.S. corporations. Commonly discussed corporate
tax reforms include policies that would broaden the tax base (i.e.,
eliminate tax expenditures) to finance reduced corporate tax rates.
Concerns that the U.S. corporate tax system inefficiently imposes a
"double tax" on corporate income has led some to consider an
integration of the corporate and individual tax systems. The
treatment of pass-through income-business income not earned by C
corporations-has also received considerable attention in tax reform
debates. How the U.S. taxes income earned abroad, and the
possibility of moving to a territorial tax system, have emerged as
important issues. Both the Obama Administration and the House
Committee on Ways and Means Chairman David Camp have released tax
reform proposals that would change the current tax treatment of
U.S. multinationals.
Congress has long been concerned with ensuring that contributions
for which tax deductions are claimed directly benefit charitable
activities. Private foundations, a traditional arrangement that
allows donations to non-active charitable entities, typically pay
grants out of earnings on donated assets. Another arrangement that
is growing rapidly is the donor advised fund (DAF). A taxpayer
contributes to a DAF, taking a tax deduction. The fund sponsor
makes grants to active charities, advised by the donor. Unlike
private foundations, DAFs are not required to pay out a certain
proportion of assets as grants each year. DAFs have become
increasingly popular in recent years, partly due to commercial
funds (e.g., Fidelity) with limited traditional charitable
interests. Provisions enacted in the Pension Protection Act of 2006
(P.L. 109-280) required DAF sponsors to report data on grants. The
data are reported at the sponsoring organization level, where
sponsoring organizations may maintain multiple individual DAF
accounts. The 2006 act also directed the Treasury Department to
study DAFs, with Congress expressing particular interest in issues
relating to potential restrictions on deductions and minimum payout
requirements. The Treasury study was released in 2011. Senator
Chuck Grassley, Senate Finance chairman at the time of the 2006
legislation, has criticized the study as being "disappointing and
nonresponsive." The Treasury did not recommend restrictions on
deductions (such as those that apply to private foundations where
grants are typically made out of earnings), appealing to the lack
of legal control by the donor. However, evidence from public
comments in the report and sponsor websites indicate that
sponsoring organizations typically follow the donor's advice, thus
suggesting that donors have effective control over donations and,
in some cases, investments. Private foundations have a 5% minimum
payout rate (and actual payouts are only slightly above that
amount). The Treasury also did not recommend a minimum payout for
DAFs, indicating that more years of data are needed. The Treasury
also appealed to the higher estimated average payout rate of DAF
sponsoring organizations (9.3% in 2006) as compared to foundations.
This report uses 2008 data to examine the minimum payout
requirement, finding results similar to those found by Treasury.
The average payout rate was 13.1%. More than 181,000 individual DAF
accounts were maintained by roughly 1,800 DAF sponsoring
organizations. Most individual accounts were maintained by
institutions with a large number of accounts (two-thirds of all DAF
accounts were held by sponsoring organizations that maintained at
least 500 accounts; nearly half of all DAF accounts were held by
commercial DAF institutions). Assets in DAF accounts were $29.5
billion, contributions were $7.1 billion, and DAF accounts paid out
$7.0 billion in grants. Because DAF accounts have heterogeneous
objectives, in some cases to manage giving with high payout rates
and in others to establish an asset base, a DAF sponsor can have a
high average payout rate although many accounts have little or no
payout. In both 2006 and 2008, a substantial share of DAF
sponsoring organizations paid out less than 5% of assets each year.
To provide some insight into the payout behavior of individual DAF
accounts, sponsoring organizations that reportedly maintained only
one DAF account in 2008 are analyzed separately. Although the
average payout rate was over 10%, more than 70% of DAF sponsoring
organizations with a single DAF account paid out less than 5%, and
53% had no grants. In contrast, less than 4% of sponsors with 100
or more accounts, accounting for 87% of DAF accounts, have a payout
rate of less than 5%. This suggests that a minimum payout rate for
sponsors would not be effective; an effective minimum payout
requirement would need to be applied to individual DAF accounts.
Currently, taxpayers may be able to claim two tax credits for
residential energy efficiency: one is scheduled to expire at the
end of 2011, whereas the other is scheduled to expire at the end of
2016. The nonbusiness energy property tax credit (Internal Revenue
Code (IRC) 25C) currently provides homeowners with a tax credit for
investments in certain high-efficiency heating, cooling, and
water-heating appliances, as well as tax credits for
energy-efficient windows and doors. For installations made during
2011, the credit rate was 10%, with a maximum credit amount of
$500. The credit available during 2011 was less than what had been
available during 2009 and 2010, when taxpayers were allowed a 30%
tax credit of up to $1,500 for making energy-efficiency
improvements to their homes. The residential energy efficient
property credit (IRC 25D), which provides a 30% tax credit for
investments in properties that generate renewable energy, such as
solar panels, is scheduled to remain available through 2016.
Advances in energy efficiency have allowed per-capita residential
energy use to remain relatively constant since the 1970s, even as
demand for energy-using technologies has increased. Experts
believe, however, that there is unrealized potential for further
residential energy efficiency. One reason investment in these
technologies might not be at optimal levels is that certain market
failures result in energy prices that are too low. If energy is
relatively inexpensive, consumers will not have a strong incentive
to purchase a technology that will lower their energy costs. Tax
credits are one policy option to potentially encourage consumers to
invest in energy-efficiency technologies. Residential
energy-efficiency tax credits were first introduced in the late
1970s, but were allowed to expire in 1985. Tax credits for
residential energy efficiency were again enacted as part of the
Energy Policy Act of 2005 (P.L. 109-58). These credits were
expanded and extended as part of the American Recovery and
Reinvestment Act of 2009 (ARRA; P.L. 111-5). The Section 25C credit
was again extended, at a reduced rate, and with a reduced cap,
through 2011, as part of the Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance
Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010 (P.L. 111-312).
Although the purpose of residential energy-efficiency tax credits
is to motivate additional energy efficiency investment, the amount
of the investment resulting from these credits is unclear.
Purchasers investing in energy-efficient property for other
reasons-for example concern about the environment-would have
invested in such property absent tax incentives, and hence stand to
receive a windfall gain from the tax benefit. Further, the fact
that the incentive is delivered as a nonrefundable credit limits
the provision's ability to motivate investment for low- and middle
income taxpayers with limited tax liability. The administration of
residential energy-efficiency tax credits has also had compliance
issues, as identified in a recent Treasury Department Inspector
General for Tax Administration (TIGTA) report. There are various
policy options available for Congress to consider regarding
incentives for residential energy efficiency. One option is to let
the existing tax incentives expire as scheduled. A second option
would be to extend or modify the current tax incentives. S. 3521,
the Family and Business Tax Cut Certainty Act of 2012, would extend
the 25C credit for two years-2012 and 2013. Another option would be
to replace the current tax credits with a grant or rebate
program-the Home Star Energy Retrofit Act of 2010 (H.R. 5019 / S.
3177 in the 111th Congress), for example. Grants or rebates could
be made more widely available, and not be limited to taxpayers with
tax liability. Enacting a grant or rebate program, however, would
have additional budgetary cost.
The majority of energy produced in the United States is derived
from fossil fuels. In recent years, however, revenue losses
associated with tax incentives that benefit renewables have
exceeded revenue losses associated with tax incentives benefitting
fossil fuels. As Congress evaluates the tax code and various energy
tax incentives, there has been interest in understanding how energy
tax benefits under the current tax system are distributed across
different domestic energy resources. In 2010, fossil fuels
accounted for 78.0% of U.S. primary energy production. The
remaining primary energy production is attributable to nuclear
electric and renewable energy resources, with shares of 11.2% and
10.7%, respectively. Primary energy production using renewable
energy resources includes both electricity generated using
renewable resources, including hydropower, as well as renewable
fuels (e.g., biofuels). The value of federal tax support for the
energy sector was estimated to be $19.1 billion in 2010. Of this,
roughly one-third ($6.3 billion) was for tax incentives that
support renewable fuels. Another $6.7 billion can be attributed to
tax-related incentives supporting various renewable energy
technologies (e.g., wind and solar). Targeted tax incentives
supporting fossil energy resources totaled $2.4 billion. This
report provides an analysis of the value of energy tax incentives
relative to primary energy production levels. Relative to their
share in overall energy production, renewables receive more federal
financial support through the tax code than energy produced using
fossil energy resources. Within the renewable energy sector,
relative to the level of energy produced, biofuels receive the most
tax-related financial support. The report also summarizes the
results of recently published studies by the Energy Information
Administration (EIA) evaluating energy subsidies across various
technologies. According to data presented in the EIA reports, the
share of direct federal financial support for electricity produced
using coal, natural gas and petroleum, and nuclear energy resources
was similar in 2007 and 2010. Between 2007 and 2010, however, the
share of federal financial support for electricity produced by
renewables increased substantially, and federal financial support
for refined coal disappeared. Projections of the annual cost of
energy-related tax provisions through 2015 show that, under current
law, tax-related support for renewable fuels will effectively
disappear after 2012. The amount of tax-related support for
renewable electricity is also scheduled to decline over time given
the recent expiration of the Section 1603 grants in lieu of tax
credits program and the scheduled expiration of other tax
incentives for renewable electricity, such as the production tax
credit (PTC). The value of energy-related tax provisions that
benefit fossil fuels is projected to remain relatively constant
over time, under current law, as most provisions that benefit
fossil fuels are permanent Internal Revenue Code (IRC) provisions.
The federal budget deficit has exceeded $1 trillion annually in
each fiscal year since 2009, and deficits are projected to
continue. Over time, unsustainable deficits can lead to reduced
savings for investment, higher interest rates, and higher levels of
inflation. Restoring fiscal balance would require spending
reductions, revenue increases, or some combination of the two.
Policymakers have considered a number of options for raising
additional federal revenues, including a carbon tax. A carbon tax
could apply directly to carbon dioxide (CO2) and other greenhouse
gas (GHG) emissions, or to the inputs (e.g., fossil fuels) that
lead to the emissions. Unlike a tax on the energy content of each
fuel (e.g., Btu tax), a carbon tax would vary with a fuel's carbon
content, as there is a direct correlation between a fuel's carbon
content and its CO2 emissions. Carbon taxes have been proposed for
many years by economists and some Members of Congress, including in
the 112th Congress. If Congress were to establish a carbon tax,
policymakers would face several implementation decisions, including
the point and rate of taxation. Although the point of taxation does
not necessarily reveal who bears the cost of the tax, this decision
involves trade-offs, such as comprehensiveness versus
administrative complexity. Several economic approaches could inform
the debate over the tax rate. Congress could set a tax rate
designed to accrue a specific amount of revenues. Some would
recommend setting the tax rate based on estimated benefits
associated with avoiding climate change impacts. Alternatively,
Congress could set a tax rate based on the carbon prices estimated
to meet a specific GHG emissions target. Carbon tax revenues would
vary greatly depending on the design features of the tax, as well
as market factors that are difficult to predict. One study
estimated that a tax rate of $20 per metric ton of CO2 would
generate approximately $88 billion in 2012, rising to $144 billion
by 2020. The impact such an amount would have on budget deficits
depends on which budget deficit projection is used. For example,
this estimated revenue source would reduce the 10-year budget
deficit by 50%, using the 2012 baseline projection of the
Congressional Budget Office (CBO). However, under CBO's alternative
fiscal scenario, the same carbon tax would reduce the 10-year
budget deficit by about 12%. When deciding how to allocate
revenues, policymakers would encounter key trade-offs: minimizing
the costs of the carbon tax to "society" overall versus alleviating
the costs borne by subgroups in the U.S. population or specific
domestic industries. Economic studies indicate that using carbon
tax revenues to offset reductions in existing taxes-labor, income,
and investment-could yield the greatest benefit to the economy
overall. However, the approaches that yield the largest overall
benefit often impose disproportionate costs on lower-income
households. In addition, carbon-intensive, trade-exposed industries
may face a disproportionate impact within a unilateral carbon tax
system. Policymakers could alleviate this burden through carbon tax
revenue distribution or through a border adjustment mechanism. Both
approaches may entail trade concerns.
|
|