|
Showing 1 - 4 of
4 matches in All Departments
In the late 1980s, the field of comparative economics and NATO
faced a similar problem: the threat of obsolescence. A predictable
reaction of those who had made major investments in both
comparative economics and NATO was to look for a new job. It was
time to say: comparative economic systems are dead, long live
comparative economic systems. The purpose of this book is to
redirect study of what we called comparative economic systems
toward analysis of the development of institutions and the effects
of alternative institutional arrangements on economic performance.
To that end, the book internalizes into a theoretical framework (1)
the effects of alternative property rights on the costs of
transactions and incentives structures, (2) the effects of the
costs of transactions and incentives on economic behavior, and (3)
the evidence for refutable implications of those effects. Analysis
here focuses on the issues, propositions and conclusions that lend
themselves to the only known scientific test: empirical
verification. Thus, this book is not about what socialism or
capitalism could have been, should have been, or should be. Nor is
it an ode to capitalism. Its purpose is not to assert that
capitalism is a better economic system than socialism. The history
of this century and the market for institutions have done that. My
purpose is to explain what is it that makes the institutions of
capitalism better in terms of economic outcome than all other
alternatives that have been tried since the beginning of recorded
history.
To understand recent developments in Eastern Europe requires a
method of analysis that is capable of internalizing into a
theoretical framework (i) the logical premises deduced from the
costs of transactions and incentive structures generated by various
institutions and (ii) the evidence for refutable implications of
those premises. The economics of property rights is such a theory.
It expands the scope of the ability of economic analysis to explain
a wide range of institutional structures and provides empirical
corroboration of its logical implications. The economics of
property rights is, then, an effective scholarly instrument that
offers more significant understanding of the three current issues
in the area of comparative economic studies: (i) evaluating the
performance of alternative institutional arrangements, (ii)
explaining the failure of socialist institutions in Eastern Europe,
and (iii) identifying the costs (political as well as economic) of
institutional reforms in that part of the world. In that sense, the
book is both timely and relevant. In the late 1980s East Europeans
crossed the threshold of fear and forced their leaders to abandon
Marxism. With that theory of history dead and buried, the cost of
current sacrifices in the pursuit of socialism has risen relative
to the present value of its expected future benefits.
In the late 1980s, the field of comparative economics and NATO
faced a similar problem: the threat of obsolescence. A predictable
reaction of those who had made major investments in both
comparative economics and NATO was to look for a new job. It was
time to say: comparative economic systems are dead, long live
comparative economic systems. The purpose of this book is to
redirect study of what we called comparative economic systems
toward analysis of the development of institutions and the effects
of alternative institutional arrangements on economic performance.
To that end, the book internalizes into a theoretical framework (1)
the effects of alternative property rights on the costs of
transactions and incentives structures, (2) the effects of the
costs of transactions and incentives on economic behavior, and (3)
the evidence for refutable implications of those effects. Analysis
here focuses on the issues, propositions and conclusions that lend
themselves to the only known scientific test: empirical
verification. Thus, this book is not about what socialism or
capitalism could have been, should have been, or should be. Nor is
it an ode to capitalism. Its purpose is not to assert that
capitalism is a better economic system than socialism. The history
of this century and the market for institutions have done that. My
purpose is to explain what is it that makes the institutions of
capitalism better in terms of economic outcome than all other
alternatives that have been tried since the beginning of recorded
history.
It was Lenin's genius to recognize the importance of [socialist]
system with all the trappings of embellishing the democracy. If the
people want a constitution. give them one. and even include the
bill of rights. If they want a parliament, give them that too. And
a system of courts. If they want a federal system create that myth
as well. Above all, let them have e 1 ecti ons, for the act of voti
ng is what the common man most clearly associates with democracy.
Give them all these, but make sure that they have no effect on how
things are run. - G. Warren Nutter Most research by Western
scholars has emphasized macroeconomics (and to a considerable
extent still does) as the method of analysis and growth rates as a
standard for evaluating the performance of different economies. In
the early 1960s Nutter raised questions about the reported growth
rates in socialist states, the importance of growth policies for
human welfare, and the abil ity of macroeconomi cs to enhance our
understandi ng of soci a 1 and economic processes. In his work,
Nutter used the standard price theory adjusted to incorporate the
incentive effects of property rights in resources. He was casti
gated for defyi ng the traditi ona 1 wi sdom. Not surprisingly,
history has validated Nutter's theoretical framework and his
conclusions.
|
You may like...
Loot
Nadine Gordimer
Paperback
(2)
R205
R164
Discovery Miles 1 640
Loot
Nadine Gordimer
Paperback
(2)
R205
R164
Discovery Miles 1 640
Loot
Nadine Gordimer
Paperback
(2)
R205
R164
Discovery Miles 1 640
The Creator
John David Washington, Gemma Chan, …
DVD
R312
Discovery Miles 3 120
|