|
Showing 1 - 12 of
12 matches in All Departments
The 2010 Deepwater Horizon incident produced the largest oil spill
that has occurred in U.S. waters, releasing more than 200 million
gallons into the Gulf of Mexico. BP has estimated the combined oil
spill costs--cleanup activities, natural resource and economic
damages, potential Clean Water Act (CWA) penalties, and other
obligations--will be approximately $41 billion. The Deepwater
Horizon oil spill raised many issues for policymakers, including
the ability of the existing oil spill liability and compensation
framework to respond to a catastrophic spill. This framework
determines (1) who is responsible for paying for oil spill cleanup
costs and the economic and natural resource damages from an oil
spill; (2) how these costs and damages are defined (i.e., what is
covered?); and (3) the degree to which, and conditions in which,
the costs and damages are limited and/or shared by other parties,
including general taxpayers. The existing framework includes a
combination of elements that distribute the costs of an oil spill
between the responsible party (or parties) and the Oil Spill
Liability Trust Fund (OSLTF), which is largely financed through a
per-barrel tax on domestic and imported oil. Responsible parties
are liable up to their liability caps (if applicable); the trust
fund ...
Air emissions from outer continental shelf (OCS) operations are
subject to different regulatory programs, depending on the location
of the operation. The Department of the Interior (DOI) has
jurisdiction over OCS sources in federal waters in the western Gulf
of Mexico and most of the central Gulf. In addition, the
Consolidated Appropriations Act, 2012 (P.L. 112-74), transferred
air emission authority in the OCS off Alaska's north coast from the
Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to DOI. EPA has jurisdiction
over sources in all other federal waters. The primary difference
between the EPA and DOI programs is rooted in the different
statutory authorities: the 1990 Clean Air Act (CAA) and the 1978
Outer Continental Shelf Lands Act (OCSLA). The primary objectives
of these statutes are different-air quality versus offshore energy
development. The two regulatory programs reflect these underlying
differences. For much of the past 30 years, these differences
received little attention, primarily because most of the federal
oil and gas resources in EPA's jurisdiction have been subject to
moratoria. In 2008, moratoria provisions expired, potentially
opening many of the areas in EPA's jurisdiction to oil and gas
leasing activity. If more OCS areas in EPA's jurisdiction are open
for oil and gas leasing, policymakers interest in these differences
will likely increase. For OCS sources in EPA's jurisdiction,
requirements depend on whether the source is located within 25
miles of a state's seaward boundary ("inner OCS sources") or beyond
("outer OCS sources"). Inner OCS sources are subject to the same
requirements as comparable onshore emission sources, which vary by
state and depend on the area's air quality status; outer sources
are subject to various CAA provisions, including the Prevention of
Significant Deterioration (PSD) program. In contrast, OCS sources
in DOI's jurisdiction are subject to air emission requirements only
if emissions would "significantly affect" onshore air quality. A
key difference between the EPA and DOI programs is the federal
emission threshold that would subject a source to substantive
requirements. For sources in EPA's jurisdiction, this is the PSD
threshold of 250 tons per year (tpy) of regulated emissions.
Sources that exceed this level would likely be subject to Best
Achievable Control Technology (BACT) and other provisions. States'
analogous thresholds that apply to inner OCS sources may be more
stringent. By comparison, a DOI OCS source applies an exemption
formula, based on distance from shore (e.g., a source 30 miles from
shore would have an emission threshold of 990 tpy). If a source
remains subject after this step, it must conduct air modeling to
assess whether its emissions would have a significant effect on
onshore air quality. In effect, this two-step process constitutes a
much less stringent threshold than EPA's 250 tpy threshold. Another
substantial difference is the time frame allotted to the agencies
for reviewing a potential source's permit (EPA) or
activity-specific plan (DOI). In addition, the EPA permit process
allows greater opportunity for input from the public. In
particular, EPA's Environmental Appeals Board offers parties a
powerful tool to compel agency review. Therefore, two identical
operations, located in separate jurisdictions, could face
considerably different requirements and procedural time frames.
Some stakeholders would likely argue that the additional
opportunities for public involvement in EPA's permit process help
create a balance between resource development and environmental
concerns. Others would likely contend these steps present
unnecessary burdens and timing uncertainty in the process.
Market-based mechanisms that limit greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions
can be divided into two types: quantity control (e.g.,
cap-and-trade) and price control (e.g., carbon tax or fee). To some
extent, a carbon tax and a cap-and-trade program would produce
similar effects: Both are estimated to increase the price of fossil
fuels, which would ultimately be borne by consumers, particularly
households. Although there are multiple tools available to
policymakers that could control GHG emissionsa "including existing
statutory authoritiesa "this report focuses on a carbon tax
approach and how it compares to its more frequently discussed
counterpart: cap-and-trade. If policymakers had perfect information
regarding the market, either a price (carbon tax) or quantity
control (cap-and-trade system) instrument could be designed to
achieve the same outcome. Because this market ideal does not exist,
preference for a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade program ultimately
depends on which variable one wants to controla "emissions or
costs. Although there are several design mechanisms that could blur
the distinction, the gap between price control and quantity control
can never be completely overcome. A carbon tax has several
potential advantages. With a fixed price ceiling on emissions (or
their inputsa "e.g., fossil fuels), a tax approach would not cause
additional volatility in energy ...
The impacts of an oil spill depend on the size of the spill, the
rate of the spill, the type of oil spilled, and the location of the
spill. Depending on timing and location, even a relatively minor
spill can cause significant harm to individual organisms and entire
populations. Oil spills can cause impacts over a range of time
scales, from days to years, or even decades for certain spills.
Superfund is the federal government's principal program for
cleaning up the nation's contaminated waste sites and protecting
public health and the environment from releases of hazardous
substances. Enacted into law as the Comprehensive Environmental
Response, Compensation, and Liability Act (CERCLA, P.L. 96-510),
the program became known as Superfund because Congress established
a large trust fund - originally supported by taxes levied on
specific petroleum products and chemicals - to provide the majority
of the program's funding needs. Although the 26-year-old program
has seen less attention compared with earlier years, Superfund
issues continue to generate debate. This report provides a
background and overview of the Superfund program and examines four
topics that received interest in recent years.
In the absence of a federal climate change program, a number of
states have taken actions that directly address greenhouse gases
(GHGs). States' efforts cover a wide range of policies. Although
much of the early activity was largely symbolic, the more recent
state actions have been more pragmatic. The states' motivations may
be as diverse as the actions themselves. Some states are motivated
by projections of climatic changes, while others expect their
policies to provide economic opportunities or other co-benefits,
such as improvements in air quality, traffic congestion, and energy
security. Another driver behind state action is the possibility of
catalyzing federal legislation.
Market-based mechanisms that limit greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions
can be divided into two types: quantity control (e.g.,
cap-and-trade) and price control (e.g., carbon tax or fee). To some
extent, a carbon tax and a cap-and-trade program would produce
similar effects: Both are estimated to increase the price of fossil
fuels, which would ultimately be borne by consumers, particularly
households. Although there are multiple tools available to
policymakers that could control GHG emissions-including existing
statutory authorities-this report focuses on a carbon tax approach
and how it compares to its more frequently discussed counterpart:
cap-and-trade.
The federal budget deficit has exceeded $1 trillion annually in
each fiscal year since 2009, and deficits are projected to
continue. Over time, unsustainable deficits can lead to reduced
savings for investment, higher interest rates, and higher levels of
inflation. Restoring fiscal balance would require spending
reductions, revenue increases, or some combination of the two.
Policymakers have considered a number of options for raising
additional federal revenues, including a carbon tax. A carbon tax
could apply directly to carbon dioxide (CO2) and other greenhouse
gas (GHG) emissions, or to the inputs (e.g., fossil fuels) that
lead to the emissions. Unlike a tax on the energy content of each
fuel (e.g., Btu tax), a carbon tax would vary with a fuel's carbon
content, as there is a direct correlation between a fuel's carbon
content and its CO2 emissions. Carbon taxes have been proposed for
many years by economists and some Members of Congress, including in
the 112th Congress. If Congress were to establish a carbon tax,
policymakers would face several implementation decisions, including
the point and rate of taxation. Although the point of taxation does
not necessarily reveal who bears the cost of the tax, this decision
involves trade-offs, such as comprehensiveness versus
administrative complexity. Several economic approaches could inform
the debate over the tax rate. Congress could set a tax rate
designed to accrue a specific amount of revenues. Some would
recommend setting the tax rate based on estimated benefits
associated with avoiding climate change impacts. Alternatively,
Congress could set a tax rate based on the carbon prices estimated
to meet a specific GHG emissions target. Carbon tax revenues would
vary greatly depending on the design features of the tax, as well
as market factors that are difficult to predict. One study
estimated that a tax rate of $20 per metric ton of CO2 would
generate approximately $88 billion in 2012, rising to $144 billion
by 2020. The impact such an amount would have on budget deficits
depends on which budget deficit projection is used. For example,
this estimated revenue source would reduce the 10-year budget
deficit by 50%, using the 2012 baseline projection of the
Congressional Budget Office (CBO). However, under CBO's alternative
fiscal scenario, the same carbon tax would reduce the 10-year
budget deficit by about 12%. When deciding how to allocate
revenues, policymakers would encounter key trade-offs: minimizing
the costs of the carbon tax to "society" overall versus alleviating
the costs borne by subgroups in the U.S. population or specific
domestic industries. Economic studies indicate that using carbon
tax revenues to offset reductions in existing taxes-labor, income,
and investment-could yield the greatest benefit to the economy
overall. However, the approaches that yield the largest overall
benefit often impose disproportionate costs on lower-income
households. In addition, carbon-intensive, trade-exposed industries
may face a disproportionate impact within a unilateral carbon tax
system. Policymakers could alleviate this burden through carbon tax
revenue distribution or through a border adjustment mechanism. Both
approaches may entail trade concerns.
Instituting policies to manage or reduce GHGs would likely impact
different states differently. Understanding these differences may
provide for a more informed debate regarding potential policy
approaches. However, multiple factors play a role in determining
impacts, including alternative design elements of a GHG emissions
reduction program, the availability and relative cost of mitigation
options, and the regulated entities' abilities to pass compliance
costs on to consumers. Three primary variables drive a state's
human-related greenhouse gas (GHG) emission levels: population, per
capita income, and the GHG emissions intensity. GHG emissions
intensity is a performance measure. In this book, GHG intensity is
a measure of GHG emissions from sources within a state compared
with a state's economic output (gross state product, GSP). The GHG
emissions intensity driver stands apart as the main target for
climate change mitigation policy, because public policy generally
considers population and income growth to be socially positive. The
intensity of carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions largely determines
overall GHG intensity, because CO2 emissions account for 85% of the
GHG emissions in the United States. As 98% of U.S. CO2 emissions
are energy-related, the primary factors that shape CO2 emissions
intensity are a state's energy intensity and the carbon content of
its energy use. Energy intensity measures the amount of energy a
state uses to generate its overall economic output (measured by its
GSP). Several underlying factors may impact a state's energy
intensity: a state's economic structure, personal transportation
use in a state (measured in vehicle miles travelled per person),
and public policies regarding energy efficiency. The carbon content
of energy use in a state is determined by a state's portfolio of
energy sources. States that utilise a high percentage of coal, for
example, will have a relatively high carbon content of energy use,
compared to states with a lower dependence on coal. An additional
factor is whether a state is a net exporter or importer of
electricity, because CO2 emissions are attributed to
electricity-producing states, but the electricity is used (and
counted) in the consuming state. Between 1990 and 2000, the United
States reduced its GHG intensity by 1.6% annually. Assuming that
population and per capita income continue to grow as expected, the
United States would need to reduce its GHG intensity at the rate of
3% per year in order to halt the annual growth in GHG emissions.
Therefore, achieving reductions (or negative growth) in GHG
emissions would necessitate further declines in GHG intensity.
|
|