|
Showing 1 - 15 of
15 matches in All Departments
For courses in Introduction to Political Science. Explore the
Fundamentals of Political Science Political Science: An
Introduction shows students how the fundamental tenets of political
science have helped important leaders make critical decisions for
centuries. The authors present a balance of theoretical
abstractions and applied reasoning to help students understand how
to make calm, rational choices when it comes to political
manipulation. This edition asks students to explore the
controversial topic of exported democracy, and whether certain
countries are ready and equipped to apply our form of government.
By examining issues such as the Iraq war and the difficulty of
adapting our own democracy in the U.S., the text prompts students
to form their own opinions about democracy and political science.
Geared toward those learning about the topic for the first time,
the authors encourage students to consider different paradigms,
viewpoints, and theories when developing their own political views.
Various explanations have been put forward as to why the Keynesian
Revolution in economics in the 1930s and 1940s took place. Some of
these point to the temporal relevance of John Maynard Keynes's The
General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936),
appearing, as it did, just a handful of years after the onset of
the Great Depression, whilst others highlight the importance of
more anecdotal evidence, such as Keynes's close relations with the
Cambridge 'Circus', a group of able, young Cambridge economists who
dissected and assisted Keynes in developing crucial ideas in the
years leading up to the General Theory. However, no systematic
effort has been made to bring together these and other factors to
examine them from a sociology of science perspective. This book
fills this gap by taking its cue from a well-established tradition
of work from history of science studies devoted to identifying the
intellectual, technical, institutional, psychological and financial
factors which help to explain why certain research schools are
successful and why others fail. This approach, it turns out,
provides a coherent account of why the revolution in macroeconomics
was 'Keynesian' and why, on a related note, Keynes was able to see
off contemporary competitor theorists, notably Friedrich von Hayek
and Michal Kalecki.
Various explanations have been put forward as to why the Keynesian
Revolution in economics in the 1930s and 1940s took place. Some of
these point to the temporal relevance of John Maynard Keynes's The
General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936),
appearing, as it did, just a handful of years after the onset of
the Great Depression, whilst others highlight the importance of
more anecdotal evidence, such as Keynes's close relations with the
Cambridge 'Circus', a group of able, young Cambridge economists who
dissected and assisted Keynes in developing crucial ideas in the
years leading up to the General Theory. However, no systematic
effort has been made to bring together these and other factors to
examine them from a sociology of science perspective. This book
fills this gap by taking its cue from a well-established tradition
of work from history of science studies devoted to identifying the
intellectual, technical, institutional, psychological and financial
factors which help to explain why certain research schools are
successful and why others fail. This approach, it turns out,
provides a coherent account of why the revolution in macroeconomics
was 'Keynesian' and why, on a related note, Keynes was able to see
off contemporary competitor theorists, notably Friedrich von Hayek
and Michal Kalecki.
The London School of Economics (LSE) has been and continues to be
one of the most important global centres for economics. With six
chapters on themes in LSE economics and 29 chapters on the lives
and work of LSE economists, this volume shows how economics became
established at the School, how it produced some of the world's
best-known economists, including Lionel Robbins and Bill Phillips,
plus Nobel Prize winners, such as Friedrich Hayek, John Hicks and
Christopher Pissarides, and how it remains a global force for the
very best in teaching and research in economics. With original
contributions from a stellar cast, this volume provides economists
- especially those interested in macroeconomics and the history of
economic thought - with the first in-depth analysis of LSE
economics.
About the Contributor(s): Robert Cording teaches English and
creative writing at College of the Holy Cross where he is the
Barrett Professor of Creative Writing. He has published six
collections of poems: Life-List, which won the Ohio State
University Press/Journal award (1987); What Binds Us to This World
(1991); Heavy Grace (1996); Against Consolation (2002); Common Life
(2006); and his newest, Walking With Ruskin (2010).
In Only So Far, Cording's poetry vacillates between complaint and
praise, lamenting and loving our "sowre-sweet dayes" as George
Herbert's poem "Bittersweet" puts it. Behind the book lies the
story of the Promised Land that Moses never quite reaches, and
those "little daily miracles" that Virginia Woolf says stand in as
a kind of recompense for the "great revelation" that never does
come. Poets and poetry readers will embrace Cording's eighth book
of poems. His work is of interest to librarians and ministers in
seminary programs.
In his poem, "The Marriage of Heaven and Hell," William Blake
hypothesized that "If the doors of perception were cleansed
everything would appear to man as it is, infinite." Of course,
Blake's "doors of perception" are both hard to clean and even
harder to keep clean. For John Ruskin, the famous 19th century art
and social critic, seeing demanded a scientist's respect for fact,
but also a love for what was being seen. These poems ask us to
attend, with devotion and care, to a world which will always remain
a mystery, but a mystery in which love calls us to the things of
this world where we may become most fully human.
Common Life looks at the various meanings of common, especially its
senses of familiar and widely known; belong or relating to the
community at large; and its twinned notions of simple and
rudimentary and vulgar and profane. The book's perspective is
religious, and is grounded in the epigraph from the Psalms: "Be
still before the Lord and wait patiently for him." The "waiting"
that is required has to do with three things: first, our desire, as
Charles Wright puts it, "to believe in belief" rather than believe;
secondly, the need for a setting aside of the self, an abandonment
of "every attempt to make something of oneself, even...a righteous
person" in the words of Dietrich Bonhoeffer; and thirdly, the
"waiting" must be as Eliot wrote in the Four Quartets a waiting
"without hope for hope would be hope of the wrong thing." If we
learn to wait in these ways, the final section of the book suggests
that we have the chance of opening ourselves to all that is
graceful within life's common bounds.
The title poem takes its name from a passage by Simone Weil, "We
must not weep so that we may not be comforted." But in this and
other poems, Robert Cording offers a more hopeful vision of our
ability to find consolation in the world we inhabit--a world
endowed will offer endless spiritual possibilities, both in nature
and within ourselves.
|
You may like...
Loot
Nadine Gordimer
Paperback
(2)
R205
R168
Discovery Miles 1 680
|